2011 OTW Elections Voting – The Process!

As we approach the voting period — polls open noon UTC 16 November (check the time in your area) and close 48 hours later, at noon UTC 18 November (check the time in your area) — we bring you one more resource: everything you ever wanted to know about the voting process!

We’re providing both textual and graphic explanations of the process, and cover how to cast your vote, how we tally the results, and plenty of examples. There’s a short version for those who just want the basics, and, below the cut, a long version for those interested in the details. Let’s go!

 


 

The Short Version

 

How to Cast Your Vote

  • You will be asked to log in with the password you chose for your voting account.
  • The ballot contains five candidates and a placeholder slot. Please leave the placeholder unranked! It is required by the voting software, but is not an actual candidate. For a more detailed explanation, check out the long version below.
  • Since there are only four available seats and five candidates, you will be asked to rank candidates in order of your first preference, followed by second preference, and so on.
  • You are not required to rank all the candidates — voters must rank at least one candidate, but otherwise can rank as many or as few as they wish.
  • Once you are satisfied with your rankings, click on the “Vote” button to cast your vote.
  • Warning: There’s no going back after you cast your vote, so please consider your choices carefully! 🙂

How We Tally Results

  • Vote tallies will be done by modified IRV (instant-runoff voting), also known as preferential voting process. (You can read more about IRV here at our elections website, or in the second half of this post.)
  • If there is a simple majority of first preferences for a candidate (i.e., the candidate is the top choice on more than 50% of the ballots), then that candidate takes one of the seats and is removed from consideration for all the other seats.
  • After a candidate is seated, the initial ballots will be recounted to fill the next seat, and the next, until all seats are filled, removing from consideration the candidates selected for the previous seats. Since each vote starts over from the original pool, based on voter preferences, each round is its own separate selection process.
  • In any instance where there is no simple majority, the following steps will be taken to determine the winner of the given seat:
    1. The candidate with the fewest first preference votes is eliminated from this cycle.
    2. The votes that would have gone to the eliminated candidate are replaced by each affected voter’s next preference, and the votes are re-tallied for the remaining candidates. This process is repeated until a 50% majority is reached and the seat is filled.
    3. Once that seat is filled, a new cycle of voting begins for the next seat, returning to the initial ballot. Any candidate already elected to a seat is removed from consideration, and all votes for those candidates are replaced by respective voters’ next preferences. After this cascade, first preference votes are re-tallied.
    4. Steps 1 and 2 are repeated until a simple majority is reached for each seat.

A Few Takeaways

  • This process lets us fill multiple seats with a single ballot and without any hierarchy among the elected candidates.
  • A candidate with the most votes overall may not necessarily get a seat if those votes aren’t as high-preference. Similarly, a candidate with few first-preference votes early on in the process may win a seat as candidates are eliminated and preferences cascade. See the graphics for examples!
  • A lowest-preference vote is different from leaving a candidate off your ballot entirely. A low-preference vote can still eventually cascade into a high-preference vote through elimination of other candidates in that cycle. Leaving a candidate unranked means they don’t get your vote at all.
  • Since, after the one required ranking, voters can rank as many or as few candidates as they wish, voters have many options for how to distribute their votes. But be careful — ranking only one candidate, for example, does not give that single vote any more “weight” and means you have no voice in ranking the remaining candidates — but it does mean none of the other candidates get any vote from you. Distribute your votes with care!

Pictures!

We’ve had several awesome contributors put together graphical representations of the process, as well as a text-based walkthrough and a step-by-step look at some sample voting data in raw tabular form. Take a look!

Below is a macro view of the process, representing votes by aggregate as slices in a pie chart.

Visual interpretation of text of this post: A graphic representing the OTW IRV process as flowchart in pie chart form

Visual interpretation of text of this post: A graphic representing the OTW IRV process as flowchart in pie chart form

Please note that Purple, who was last to be eliminated from the first cycle and had many first preference votes in the first round of that cycle, did not get a seat in this example. Meanwhile, Red, who had relatively few first preference votes in the first cycle, won a seat in the second cycle. Wondering how this can work? Check out the next set of images, which shows how the votes move around!

This next set of images provides a closer look, taking a very small data sample and showing the individual votes and how preferences cascade as candidates are eliminated. (Click on the images for full-sized versions.)

Visual interpretation of text of this post: a graphic representing the OTW IRV process as colored tiles in a grid Visual interpretation of text of this post: a graphic representing the OTW IRV process as colored tiles in a grid Visual interpretation of text of this post: a graphic representing the OTW IRV process as colored tiles in a grid

The rest of this set of images, as well as the long version of the IRV explanation, the text-based example, and the tabular example are all below!


Visual interpretation of text of this post: a graphic representing the OTW IRV process as colored tiles in a grid Visual interpretation of text of this post: a graphic representing the OTW IRV process as colored tiles in a grid Visual interpretation of text of this post: a graphic representing the OTW IRV process as colored tiles in a grid Visual interpretation of text of this post: a graphic representing the OTW IRV process as colored tiles in a grid Visual interpretation of text of this post: a graphic representing the OTW IRV process as colored tiles in a grid Visual interpretation of text of this post: a graphic representing the OTW IRV process as colored tiles in a grid Visual interpretation of text of this post: a graphic representing the OTW IRV process as colored tiles in a grid Visual interpretation of text of this post: a graphic representing the OTW IRV process as colored tiles in a grid Visual interpretation of text of this post: a graphic representing the OTW IRV process as colored tiles in a grid Visual interpretation of text of this post: a graphic representing the OTW IRV process as colored tiles in a grid Visual interpretation of text of this post: a graphic representing the OTW IRV process as colored tiles in a grid Visual

Please note that B had the most votes overall, but is the only candidate to not win a seat, because those votes were lower-preference.

 


 

The Long Version: IRV, a Closeup View

 

How it works

Instant Runoff Voting is an election system that allows a decision with a single round of voting by asking voters to rank their choices in order of preference. The biggest advantage of this system for our purposes is that generally, this eliminates the need for additional balloting to break a tie and elects an equal, rather than hierarchical, cohort of candidates.

We use Drupal’s decisions module, set to instant-runoff voting (aka preferential voting). Voters use a ballot that allows them to give a numerical rank to all candidates. Attempts to assign the same rank to multiple candidates are disallowed. Any candidate lacking a rank is given no weighting in the ballot. If a voter casts a ballot which ranks candidate A as fourth preference and candidate B as second preference, but lists no first or third preference, then the system represents candidate B as that voter’s first preferences, and candidate A as their next most preferred candidate.

IRV is a system that determines only a single winner, and as the OTW elections are meant to fill all available board seats without establishing a hierarchy or ranking for the incoming members, the decisions software is reset after each round of seat selection to determine each winner — but this time with elections staff editing the ballot to delete the winner of the previous seat. This removes the winner, and their rankings, from the results, leaving all of the other candidates, and their rankings, in place. Any gaps left by the eliminated candidates are filled by cascading each voter’s preferences for the remaining candidates, in the same manner as the example above where a voter picked only a second and fourth preference. The system then automatically tallies the votes again, returning a second winner.

This process nearly eliminates the need for tiebreaker votes. If there is a tie and there are enough seats available to seat all the tied candidates, then all those candidates are seated and, if necessary, the process can continue. If there are not enough seats for all tied candidates, then the number of second preferences votes for those candidates will be tallied next, and so on until the seats are filled. Only in the extremely unlikely event of a tie for insufficient seats where all preferences match exactly is additional voting necessary.

It is important to understand that this system revolves around relational voter preferences — all candidates in relation to each other, rather than absolutely. This is what is behind the cascade of preferences as candidates are eliminated, and also what allows this system to fill multiple seats with no hierarchy among the elected candidates. The cascade of votes makes it difficult (as well as undesirable) to draw clear hierarchies, even in the first cycle, where the candidate with the most votes overall is not necessarily the candidate who will end up with majority first preference and win a seat.

Here is the process across multiple cycles, step-by-step:

Cycle One (if there is no clear majority winner):

  1. First preference votes are tallied.
  2. The candidate with the fewest first preference votes is eliminated for this round, and all votes for that candidate are replaced by that particular voter’s next preference.
  3. The process is repeated, each time eliminating the candidate with the least votes and substituting the voter’s next preferences for the remaining candidates, until a clear majority of first preferences is determined. That candidate is seated.

Where things get tricky is in Round 2, where you return to the initial ballots, but then the election staff eliminates the winner of Round 1. Then, if there is no simple majority after votes are tallied, they eliminate the candidate with the least number of first preference votes:

Cycle Two:

  1. All votes for the candidate who won Round 1 are replaced by each affected voter’s next preferences.
  2. First preference votes are then tallied, just like the first round.
  3. If there is no simple majority winner, the candidate with the least votes is eliminated, and the process continues just as it did before until a majority is reached.

Cycle Three:

The third round also starts over from the entire original vote pool, removing votes for all candidates who have already been elected and substituting that voter’s next choice.

Since each round starts over from the original pool, based on voter preferences, each round is its own separate selection process.

More examples!

To see a full example of a single cycle with sample candidates and a many votes, check out this text-based walkthrough of the process, which shows the votes and winners for each step of the process: IRV Walkthrough. The link goes to a series of web pages that walk you through the elimination rounds of a single cycle.

To see an example of raw voting data in tabular form, check out this series of spreadsheets: IRV Spreadsheets. This works from the same data as the above example, but follows on from the first cycle through all four cycles. Click through the sheets, numbered at the top, to watch the process in action. This example also includes a tie, showing how the modified IRV process nearly eliminates the need for tiebreaker votes.

The placeholder slot

Wondering about the placeholder slot? Here’s how that works: our balloting system allows voters to rank all candidates, independent of the number of seats — so if there are 7 candidates, all 7 can be ranked. However, a recent security upgrade to Drupal’s decisions module — the software we use to run the election — changed this. The software now allows voters to rank all but one candidate — so if there are 7 candidates, you would only be able to rank 6 of them.

Despite the software change, we prefer to give voters the choice of opting into (ranking) or opting out of (leaving off the ballot) each and every candidate. Giving a candidate lowest preference is a different choice from leaving a candidate off the ballot altogether, since low preferences can eventually cascade up into first preferences as other candidates are eliminated.

For this reason, we have added one extra “candidate” to the ballot: a placeholder candidate that will take the unranked slot. You can still leave other candidates off your ballot, or you can choose to rank them all.

We apologize for this somewhat awkward workaround, and hope to modify the software before next year’s election so that it will no longer be necessary.

 


 

We’d like to thank the many contributors who have helped make this post possible, including Aja, Allison Morris, Candra Gill, Ira Gladkova, Kristen Murphy, Renay, and Seventhe Dragomire.

We hope this post has helped you understand the voting system and given you tools to help plan your vote. Happy voting!

Announcement
  1. Enigel commented: This has indeed helped understand more! I've re-read this post, since elections are coming round again soon, and after a few years it finally makes sense. ;-) (Especially the part about relational preferences. I was wondering why was this system chosen, apart from the "instant" aspect, so yes, it makes sense.) One thing: the link to full-size https://transformativeworks.org/sites/default/files/otw_irv6.JPG is broken - it should be https://transformativeworks.org/sites/default/files/otw_irva6.JPG (The bubbles are very helpful for us visual learners!)